1. Questions that beg
to be asked
US and European corporate media, political pundits and �Iran experts�
have spent countless hours discussing the June presidential election in Iran. Yet, they
have utterly failed to ask a number of central questions that beg to be asked.
Why did Mir Hossein Mousavi, the main rival of President
Ahmadinejad, declare himself the winner while voting was still in progress?
Since there are no exit polls in Iran, how could he have known for
sure he was the winner when the votes were not yet counted? (According to some
accounts he declared victory barely an hour after the polls closed; according
to others he did so hours before the polls closed. His own and his campaign�s
statements show that, in fact, they declared victory before, during and
immediately after the voting. For example, his wife Zahra Rahnavard, one of his
major campaigners, told BBC News during an interview the day before the
Election Day that her husband would score a big, four-to-one, win against
Ahmadinejad; and that the only way Ahmadinejad could win would be through
fraud. How did she know that?)
How could this premature announcement of victory be
explained? Was it because Mr. Mousavi�s campaign managers led him to become
truly delusional, sincerely believing he could not lose? Or, was it a
deliberate preemptive measure to replace Ahmadinejad regardless of who actually
won at the ballot box?
And why did Mr. Mousavi declare the election stolen the
moment he learned he had actually lost? How did he know it was stolen, except
for the fact that the official account contradicted his campaign�s wishful
projections? For at least three days his claim of �stolen� election remained
just that. Even when he was forced to substantiate his allegation, he submitted
to the Guardian Council, the body responsible for overseeing the election, a
long list of electoral irregularities that, while true, did not constitute a
pattern of coordinated or systematic effort at stealing the election. [1]
Further, what compelled Mr. Mousavi to go for the jugular --
either another election or a �green revolution� -- instead of going through the
country�s legal and institutional channels, which have administered or presided
over ten clean, undisputed presidential elections since the 1979 revolution?
Knowing that another election was out of the question, he immediately called
upon his supporters to take to the streets and start the projected revolution.
Why?
It is often argued that Mr. Mousavi�s rationale for
sidestepping the institutional and legal frameworks governing the electoral
process was because he did not trust them. But this argument raises even more
questions about his mysterious behavior. He was nominated as a presidential
candidate within Iran�s
electoral laws and procedures. On the basis of those laws and procedures, he
was vetted and approved by the Guardian Council, the responsible authority for
overseeing the election. The Guardian Council�s screening of candidates before
they can run for president is often criticized as undemocratic, and therefore
objectionable. But that was obviously not a problem for Mr. Mousavi as he went through
and came out of the screening process with flying colors. And he ran a highly
successful and well-financed (indeed, extravagant) campaign without any legal
or institutional obstacles. Why, then, the sudden about face: the abrupt
rejection of and rebellion against the country�s electoral laws and
institutions?
Mr. Mousavi used the term �green revolution� to label his
campaign. But color-coded revolutions, as carried out in Eastern
Europe and former Soviet republics, are synonymous with electoral
coups: a scheme of participating in an election process with the intention of
not accepting defeat at the ballot box. The question then arises: �Why would
there be a �green revolution� prepared prior to the vote, especially if Mousavi
and his supporters were as confident of victory as they claim?� as astutely
pointed out by Paul Craig Roberts. [2]
2. Electoral coups as
color-coded revolutions
Having mulled over these questions long and hard, I can
think of only two interpretations of Mr. Mousavi�s assertion of �stolen
elections.� The charitable interpretation is that he was led by his campaign
architects to honestly believe he could not lose. The more likely
interpretation, however, is that he colluded with the powerful interests behind
his campaign not to accept defeat. Either way, the inescapable conclusion is
that contrary to Mr. Mousavi�s claim that Ahmadinejad stole the election, it
seems more likely that, in fact, it was his own campaign architects who were
determined to highjack the election.
Although his campaign managers characterize his unsuccessful
bid to unseat Ahmadinejad as �green revolution,� post-election revelations
indicate, however, that it was more akin to an attempt at a political or
electoral coup than a bona fide campaign that is prepared to accept the
Majority vote. It is one thing to use the electorate�s discontent with the
status to win an election -- most politicians running for public office do
this. It is quite another, however, to take advantage of their dissatisfaction
to defy the election results. [3]
Whether by chance or by design or by the logic of objective
circumstance on the ground, Mr. Mousavi�s �green revolution� bore an uncanny
resemblance to previous color-coded revolutions in Eastern Europe and former
Soviet Republics. Like the campaigns to bring to power pro-market and
pro-Western regimes in Georgia
(2003) and Ukraine
(2004), his campaign was engineered and managed by powerful business interests
who are known to be pursuing similar objectives. As with the campaign headed by
Mr. Mousavi, the campaigns led by Saakashvili in Georgia and Yushchenko
in Ukraine styled themselves reformist and democratic while promoting the
neoliberal, or trickle-down, economic policies favored by big business and/or
transnational capital.
Social forces behind
�color revolutions� are rooted in the transnational capitalists� drive to
integrate and unify global markets, more or less after the model of unbridled
economic liberalism. The powerful economic interests behind that drive operate
from both the core capitalist countries, especially the US, as well as
the �peripheral� or less-developed countries targeted for �regime change.�
Their activities, formally billed as �non-violent� or �soft-power� operations,
are designed to supplement the long-standing globalization mission of
multilateral institutions such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the
World Bank, and the World Trade Organization (WTO).
On the US side, such
activities are carried out by a number of government-funded think tanks like
the National Endowment for Democracy (NED), the Central Intelligence Agency
(CIA), the United States Institute for Peace (USIP), Center for International
Private Enterprise, the International Republican Institute, National Democratic
Institute, Foundation for Democracy in Iran, United States Agency for
International Development (USAID), and a number of other agencies and NGOs. On
the side of the countries targeted for �reform� and �regime change,� architects
of �color revolutions� are interchangeably called the oligarchs, the nouveau
riche, or the comprador bourgeoisie. Who are these indigenous allies of
transnational capitalism?
Following the collapse of the Soviet
Union, large scale privatization of public enterprises became
rampant in Russia
and other former republics of the Soviet Union.
All kinds of �experts� of nation-building on a capitalist basis, especially
neoliberal economic advisors from the United States, played key roles in
crafting those highly scandalous privatization schemes. By virtue of
privatizing public property on the cheap, many of the leaders of the newly
independent states managed to become very rich very quickly -- they have since
come to be known as oligarchs. (Michael Hudson, Professor of Economics at the University of Missouri, calls them �kleptocrats,�
denoting corrupt ruling elites that seek power and personal gain at the expense
of the public.)
But the newly acquired private fortunes needed freedom from
the remnants of the Soviet-era legal and institutional �constraints� such as
labor laws (that guaranteed life-time employment), universal healthcare,
cradle-to-grave free education, and the like. To break free from these
�restraining� laws and traditions, the oligarchs also needed political or state
power that would go along with their economic power, i.e., would allow them to
conduct their economic affairs according to unhindered market mechanism.
The oligarch�s desire to bring about legal, political and
institutional changes to better serve their nefarious economic interests
coincided with the globalization designs of US imperialism to bring about
�regime change� in those countries in order to carry out pro-American economic
and foreign policies. This explains the convergence of the interests of the
imperialist and the home-grown bourgeoisies on removing �undesirable regimes�
from power.
Most commentators trace the origins of the US doctrine of
�color revolutions,� and the concomitant concept of �soft power� or
�non-violent struggle,� to the 1990s. But a number of political historians,
including Thierry Meyssan, president of the Voltaire Network, trace it back to
the 1970s: �This concept appeared in the 90s, but its roots lie in the American
public debate of the 70s-80s. After a string of revelations about
CIA-instigated coups around the world, as well as the dramatic disclosures of
the Church and Rockefeller Senate Committees, Admiral Stansfield Turner was
given the task by President Carter to clean up the agency and to stop
supporting �local dictatorships.� Furious, the American Social Democrats
(SD/USA) left the Democratic Party and sided with Ronald Reagan. . . . After
Reagan was elected, he charged them with pursuing the American interference
policy, this time using different methods. This is how the National Endowment
for Democracy (NED) was created in 1982 and the United States Institute for
Peace (USIP) in 1984.� [4]
Philip Giraldi,
former officer of the United States Central Intelligence Agency, presently a
partner in an international security consultancy (Cannistraro Associates),
describes the US designs of �soft power� and/or �color revolutions� as follows:
�Where regime change coming out of Washington might once have been done
covertly by the CIA, it is now done openly by a number of organizations that
are ostensibly �private� but are in reality funded by the government, the NGOs
and others that Vladimir Putin and others have been complaining about. . . . The
money and effort that is being channeled through NGOs is being used to change
the way many countries are governed, to make them become more democratic or at
least more cooperative with Europe and the United States. The
countries on the receiving end are more often than not completely aware of what
is going on. Frequently, the Western media jumps on the band wagon to
complete the job, hailing the arrival of democracy in yet another poor
benighted land while carefully ignoring the corruption of the newly minted
democratic leaders.
�The National Endowment for Democracy (NED), with its
bipartisan International Republican Institute and its National Democratic
Institute wings, is the chief culprit, but the US Agency for International
Development also is involved, funded under the Freedom Support Act. The
National Endowment for Democracy, which funds changing governments overseas and
has virtually no oversight, would in any other guise be proscribed as a
dangerous underground group. . . . What do these organizations do when they set
out to overturn a government? They would not be so unwise as to appear
adversarial or cast themselves as revolutionaries, so they instead describe
themselves in the most benign terms while becoming enablers for others who wish
to �create democracy.� They understand above all that the ability to protest
and force the change of governments is not new but that the new technologies
have changed the entire game.� [5]
The degree and details of the US involvement in the Post-Soviet
color revolutions may be debatable. There is no question, however, that the US
money, media and �expertise� played a significant role in the success of those
revolutions. [6]
Briefly, here is how color-coded revolutions in Eastern Europe and for Soviet republics such as Georgia and Ukraine were
carried out.
1. During the campaign season the oligarchs (in concert with
the US
media and other agents of �soft power� projection) started extensive and
exaggerated negative campaigns against the targeted incumbents in their
respective countries. This was designed to frighten the people of the prospects
of the re-election of the incumbents.
2. Also prior to the election day, the oligarchs and their
external allies circulated exaggerated projections of their candidates� chances
for victory, portraying them as invincible, often with the help of self-serving
pre-election polls. (US
money, �experts� and media played important roles in conducting such convenient
opinion polls.)
3. On the election day, the oligarch�s candidates declared
victory either before the polls were actually closed, or before the official
accounts of the voting results were announced. This was designed to discredit
the official count of the votes cast. The longer the time period between the
opposition�s premature, or preemptive, declaration of victory and the time of
the official announcement of the voting results, the more plausible the
opposition�s claim that the government must have been �fixing� the votes.
4. As soon as the official results were announced,
contradicting the opposition�s premature victory announcement, the oligarchs
and their candidate cried foul: �we told you they were stealing your votes.�
5. Determined not to accept defeat, the opposition then
called upon their supporters (and the public at large) to take to the streets
to �defend democracy� and retrieve their �stolen votes.�
If the scenario thus painted seems like a conspiracy theory,
it is because those color revolutions were actually conspiratorial designs.
�The main mechanism of the �color revolutions� consists in focusing popular
anger on the desired target. This is an aspect of the psychology of the masses
which destroys everything in its path and against which no reasonable argument
can be opposed. The scapegoat is accused of all the evils plaguing the country
for at least one generation. The more he resists, the angrier the mob gets.
After he gives in or slips away, the normal division between his opponents and
his supporters reappears.� [7]
Just as the oligarchs in Eastern Europe and former Soviet
republics acquired their riches and resources by virtue of their positions
within the state apparatus, so too the Iranian rich and powerful have gained
their unearned assets by virtue of their positions within the state
bureaucracy. Also like their post-Soviet counterparts in Eastern Europe, Iran�s
nouveau riche have gradually begun to view welfare-state programs, which were
put in place immediately following the 1979 revolution, burdensome and
constraining to the unhindered utilization of their ill-begotten capital. Not
surprisingly, they too have acquired an appetite for a �color revolution� to
unseat Ahmadinejad�s government and remove the �constraints� of welfare-state
to the �efficient� operations of unbridled market system.
It follows that economic conditions, or business interests,
favoring a �color revolution� in Iran have actually existed or
evolved within its own socio-economic circumstances. Although powerful external
forces of destabilization may have magnified the impact and the influence of
internal forces of �regime change,� the fact remains that tendencies to replace
Ahmadinejad also evolved domestically. It is therefore critically important to
avoid the simplistic either-or arguments when discussing the destabilizing
roles played by external and internal forces in the scheme of �regime change�
in Iran.
Since there was a convergence of interests between the two forces over the
removal of Ahmadinejad from power, their efforts to achieve this goal
inevitably reinforced each other -- regardless of the existence, or lack
thereof, of any active or conscious link between the two.
Contrary to the widespread perception in the West,
especially in the United
States, the 1979 revolution in Iran was not
simply the product of a religious or culturally-driven rebellion against
Western values. More importantly, it was the product of a truly national front
against the rule of the dictatorial Shah (king) and his imperial supporters
from outside. It included both secular and religious nationalists, the
socialist groups, and the masses of the poor and working people who were driven
by hopes of a better life following the success of the revolution.
Not only did the grassroots demand from the revolution basic
political rights such as civil equality and individual liberty, but more
importantly, certain economic rights such as universal healthcare and a strong
public support for education. The working class, headed by strong and militant
unions, developed especially high expectations of better living conditions of
the revolution. Not only did they play a crucial role in bringing down the
Shah�s regime (by bringing major industries, especially the oil industry, to a
standstill), but also managed to run all the major industries -- in effect, the
national economy -- independently for nearly a year, during and immediately
after the revolution.
The grassroots� hopes and expectations that were thus
enlivened by the revolution were further reinforced by the 8-year (1980-88) war
with Iraq,
and the concomitant economics of war. For one thing, the war-time conditions
led to an even bigger public sector economy, which provided for the basic needs
of millions of the poor and working people. For another, the war was fought
disproportionately at the expense of the poor and working classes who made
heroic sacrifices in fending off the imperialist instigated invasion of Iran by Saddam
Hussein. Not surprisingly, those who made the lion�s share of sacrifices in
defending the country also expected certain economic rights in terms of
employment, education, healthcare, and the like.
Following the war, however, the successive administrations
of Presidents Rafsanjani (1989-97) and Khatami (1997-2005) methodically
hammered away at the foundations of social safety-net programs (that were put
in place by virtue of the early revolutionary years and the war economy) in
order to free market forces form the �constraints� of welfare state. President
Rafsanjani�s �structural adjustment program,� a neoliberal market
liberalization promoted by the International Monetary Fund around the world,
which hastened the pace of deregulation and privatization of public
enterprises, was bitterly resisted by the overwhelming majority of the Iranian
people.
As the 16 years of Rafsanjani and Khatami presidencies
gradually deregulated the market and privatized public property, they also
facilitated the rise of Iran�
nouveau riche, or oligarchs. Ordinary Iranians resent the nouveau riche (who
are sarcastically called agha-zadeh,
or the sons and daughters of the corrupt elite) not because they are rich, but
because most of them became rich by virtue of what amounts to embezzlement and
predatory privatization of public property. Resentment is especially poignant
among the ranks of the poor and working classes who not long ago fought
valiantly for eight years to preserve both the revolutionary ideals and national
sovereignty, but are now witnessing what they view as �betrayal� of those
ideals by the former revolutionaries who have become corrupt and compromising
elders within the state and other powerful bureaucracies, including many in the
clerical establishment.
The 1979 revolution placed many critical issues on the
national agenda, but left most of them largely unresolved. This was especially
true concerning issues of class or economic justice. In a sense, the revolution
left the fate of the Iranian economy in a limbo: neither capitalism nor
socialism, in the classic senses of these terms. This explains the persistent
tug of war, or class struggle, between proponents of social justice, on the one
hand, and those of economic liberalism, on the other. It also explains the
continuing or recurring revolutionary atmosphere in Iran. It further explains the rise
of Mahmoud Ahmadinejad to Iran�s
presidency as a clear expression of an unmistakable blowback against the rich
and corrupt establishment.
3. The rise of
Ahmadinejad
When Khatami�s second term as president expired in 2005,
Ahmadinejad entered the presidential race as the candidate of the �voiceless�
grassroots, determined to reverse what he called �the revolution�s steady slide
to the Right� during the 16 years (1989-2005) of the Rafsanjani and Khatami
administrations. After a hiatus of eight years, Rafsanjani too entered the 2005
presidential race. The initially-asymmetrical competition between the
well-known and all-powerful Rafsanjani and the little-known Ahmadinejad, one of
the seven children of a blacksmith, seemed to resemble a case of David versus
Goliath. Apprehensive of Rafsanjani�s big-business solutions to economic
problems, ordinary Iranians mobilized behind Ahmadinejad, thereby delivering Rafsanjani
the defeat of his lifetime. It is generally believed in Iran that
having lost at the ballot box, Rafsanjani and his elite allies set out to
sabotage Ahmadinejad�s agenda of economic reform that would favor the poor and
working classes.
Contrary to most politicians who renege on their campaign
promises after they are elected, Ahmadinejad has proven relentless in pursuing
the fulfillment of his campaign promises. His 2005 campaign gave voice to
segments of the Iranian people previously shut out from the process. He has
since stood firm for them. At a public event in October 2006, Ahmadinejad
announced the idea of �Justice Shares,� where the state would divide shares
(stocks) to some major state-owned companies among 4.6 million of Iran�s
grassroots. These shareholders of national wealth would pay only half of the
market price for the stocks they thus received; the other half would be paid
over time from the proceeds, or dividends, of those share.
Although his political opponents have occasionally called
him a �socialist� (presumably designed to stir up the religious establishment
against him), Ahmadinejad is no socialist. Nor are the social safety net
programs he advocates as radical as those promoted by Hugo Chavez in Venezuela, or Evo Morales in Bolivia. He is
neither against private property, nor a market economy. He is for a mixed
economy in which state ownership in important industries (such as oil and gas)
would coexist side-by-side with a regulated market structure that would not
leave anyone unprotected against the woes and vagaries of an unbridled market
mechanism. He trusts neither the big, unregulated business, nor the strong,
independent workers� organizations. Although he is sympathetic of the workers�
needs and struggles, he is wary of their independent power; it is a
paternalistic, �big brother� or authoritarian kind of support and sympathy.
When Ahmadinejad took office in 2005, he set out to fight
and eliminate the �oil mafia,� the powerful private interests (including the
Rafsanjani family) that have lucrative stakes in the publicly-owned oil
industry, and who have constantly been pushing for privatization of the
industry. He tried to wrest control of key ministries, especially oil,
replacing the market-friendly officials appointed by Rafsanjani and Khatami
with his own choices. It was not until 2007, however, that he was able to
install his candidate for oil minister, also head of the National Iranian Oil
Company (NOIC), Gholamhossein Nozari. Indeed, for nearly a year, Ahmadinejad
did not have a full cabinet because a number of his choices were rejected by
powerful opponents in the fiercely contentious parliament.
The oil and gas revenue, which would be profits of giant oil
companies in a country like the United
States, is instead used to fund most of
government investments and expenditures. This is the source of government�s
ability to invest in both human capital such as health and education, and
physical capital or infrastructure such as roads, bridges, mass transit, dams,
and the like -- investments that are crucial to the ideals of long-term
economic growth and social prosperity. (Ideally, a nation should not be
dependent so much on its natural resources for its budgetary needs; but Iran, like many
other less-developed countries, has not yet reached the level of
industrialization necessary to be less dependent on revenue from oil.)
Budgetary decisions on the allocation of national resources
have traditionally been quite centralized in Iran: all national revenues, coming
largely from the sale of oil and natural gas, would be collected by and then
allocated from Tehran.
This mechanism disproportionately favored major metropolitan centers at the
expense of the provinces and the countryside. It also unduly favored major
government contractors and influential corporate interests at the expense of
small, less-competitive enterprises and producers. Since his election in 2005,
Ahmadinejad has been fighting hard to bring about a modicum of fairness in the
allocation of national resources by trying to somewhat decentralize budgetary
decision making, and redirect an equitable share of resources to the grassroots
and the countryside.
While his efforts to bring a degree of fairness in the
distribution of national resources have been very popular with the grassroots,
they have incensed the affluent, economic �experts,� and technocratic or
managerial elite. �The president has especially enraged the managerial class
with his wildly popular monthly rallies in the provinces, where he orders
funding on the spot for the infrastructure needs of common folks. . . . Several
of his advisors and cabinet ministers and even a Central Bank�s director
general have stepped down or been dismissed after challenging the president�s �unscientific�
intervention in markets. At least one of them, former economic affairs
minister Davood Danesh Jafari, campaigned for a rival [presidential] candidate
this spring.� [8]
Ahmadinejad�s opponents have labeled his spending
adjustments in favor of the poor and working classes as �handouts� that, as
Rafsanjani put it, would lead to gadaparvari
(nurturing poverty). This sinister argument (which, by the way, is typical of
the champions of laissez-faire economics) suffers from a number of
shortcomings.
To begin with, the rich and powerful who characterize
Ahmadinejad�s social spending as �handouts� are not very consistent in their
calls for the curtailment or abolition of government subsidies. Following the
1979 revolution and the war economy of the 1980-88 period, the government
subsidized many consumer items that benefited all citizens regardless of their
income levels! Although some modifications have been made over the years, many
such blanket, or �class-neutral,� subsidies remain in effect to this day. These
include subsidies for a number of food items, especially bread, as well as
sources of energy or fuel, both home-heating and motor vehicle fuels. This
means that the wealthy buy such subsidized items at the same prices as do the
needy!
Furthermore, because the affluent consume relatively more of
the subsidized goods and services, they end up benefiting disproportionately
more from government subsidies than the grassroots. �Gasoline subsidies are an
example where the rich benefit most because they tend to have bigger,
gas-guzzling vehicles, while the poor may not even be able to afford a small
car. . . . �Currently, subsidies are not useful and have the reverse effect of
what was intended,� he [Ahmadinejad] said in comments carried by the official
newspaper Iran, adding that 70
percent of subsidy spending ended up with the country�s richest 30 percent.� [9]
President Ahmadinejad has been trying hard to bring an end
to the insanity of subsidizing the wealthy. �Rationalization of subsidies� (bahineh kardan-e subsidha), as Ahmadinejad has frequently
explained, means eliminating price subsidies altogether, and then having the
government use the financial resources thus saved for direct assistance to the
needy -- similar to the use of food stamps or cash payments to the needy in the
United States. Not only is this a more sensible system of subsidizing the
needy, it will also save the government money because the funds saved by virtue
of cutting blanket price subsidies is much more than direct subsidies to the
needy, according to both the Ahmadinejad administration and independent
financial experts. Ahmadinejad�s efforts to alter a perverse subsidy system,
however, have so far been successfully blocked by the powerful interests who
oppose them, by the hypocritical forces who label assistance to the needy
�handouts� but are unwilling to give up their own subsidies.
Secondly, and more importantly, it is sheer cynicism to
characterize social spending and assistance to the needy as �handouts.� While
social expenditures include some cash disbursements to the needy, the major
bulk of those expenditures can be more appropriately called investment in
public capital formation. These include both human capital, such as health and
education, and physical capital, such as mass transit, communications systems,
transportation networks, dams, and the like.
Thanks to government support there is now guarantee of
medical care regardless of the ability to pay. Rural areas have gained
electricity, paved roads, running (piped) water, crop insurance, insurance
against natural disasters, and access to health and education services. Of
course, Ahmadinejad does not get all the credit for these services because most
of them came to existence by virtue of the 1979 revolution. He does, however,
get credit for expanding and reinforcing them, as they were largely neglected
by the previous two administrations, headed by Presidents Khatami and
Rafsanjani.
During my recent trip to Iran (mid-March to early May), as I
traveled to the countryside, including tribal communities, I learned that the
government has in recent years boosted health insurance programs for both
farming and tribal communities. Each village now has a full-time nurse, and
every cluster of villages has a medical clinic that is built or housed in a
centrally-located village. I also learned that family planning and the use of
contraceptives are vigorously encouraged by government-sponsored health experts
in the countryside.
Government spending on public health has paid off
handsomely: according to World Bank statistics, in the three decades since the
1979 revolution, life expectancy in Iran has moved up from 59 to 71; child
mortality at birth has gone down from 95 to below 30 per thousand; immunization
rate (for Measles and DPT) has gone up from below 40% to 99%; and the average
family size has shrunken from nine to four, which of course means the birth
rate has gone down from seven to two.
The government also provides free education up to and
including the college level for public schools and universities. (Private education
institutions, which are quite expensive, do not get public assistance.) Even
the children of tribal communities who travel with their live stock along the
grazing routes now have access to free education. This is made possible by
having (mobile) teachers travel with tribal communities. I have met a number of
these teachers during my visits to Iran. One of them is a nephew of mine, who
told me that one small tribe had only three school-age kids. Nonetheless, the
education authorities of the region had assigned a teacher to the tribe to
teach their children. Not surprisingly, according to World Bank statistics,
literacy rate in Iran has during the past two decades moved up from 63% to
slightly over 80%.
Although women are required to comply with the official
dress code, they are encouraged (by both their families and the government) to
excel in educational and professional pursuits. The results have been quite
impressive. Women now constitute the majority of university students. They are
doctors, engineers, teachers, scientists, writers, artists, salespersons, and
even taxi drivers. More and more women are joining the workforce, despite the
very high level of unemployment, which is largely due to criminal economic
sanctions and military threats from abroad.
Characterizing social spending and government assistance to
the needy as �handouts� is both cynical and elitist. It is also a disingenuous
argument designed to camouflage the pro-capital biases of big-business
interests. Proponents of economic liberalism have always used this snobbish
argument to cut social spending in order to keep taxes low on the affluent, and
deny the poor and working classes a decent degree of living conditions.
Not only is this selfish attitude of the wealthy unfair to
those who suffer from the woes and vagaries of an unregulated capitalist
economy, it is also short-sighted and counterproductive in terms of their own
long-term interests. Instead of viewing social spending on infrastructure as a
long-term investment that will help sustain and promote economic vitality, they
view it as a burden, or overhead, that must be cut as much as possible. By
focusing on the current, short-term balance sheets, they seem to be oblivious
to the indirect, long-term returns to social spending. Evidence shows, however,
that neglect of public capital formation can undermine long-term health,
prosperity and productivity of a people.
Fighting corruption and trying to curtail or retrieve what
he calls the �unearned� incomes of the corrupt establishment was one of the
major agenda items of Ahmadinejad�s presidential campaign. Not only did this
frighten the nouveau riche, but also many of the religious authorities who are
not necessarily wealthy but whose comfortable positions of prestige and stature
would be threatened by Ahmadinejad�s efforts to whittle down what he has called
redundant bureaucracies. The elite had had enough.
Frightened by Ahmadinejad�s crusade-like commitment to fight
corruption, waste and costly privileges, champions of economic liberalism
poured money into Mousavi�s election campaign to unseat him. The presidential
election of last June was their last stand against their clearly populist
nemesis, Mahmoud Ahmadinejad. (It is regrettable, as well as ironic, that while
Ahmadinejad and his co-thinkers are at loggerheads with major segments of the
clerical establishment, most of the Iranian opposition abroad fail to make any
distinction between the two forces. Instead, in a largely emotional approach,
they tend to lump all factions of Iran�s ruling circles together as a
cohesive or monolithic body that pursues the same political or policy agenda.)
4. Mousavi and his
reform agenda
The Opposition promoted Mousavi as the reform candidate. In his campaign
speeches he frequently complained that Ahmadinejad�s administration was
obstructing progress because it resisted reform toward an �efficient� market
system. What was his reform agenda?
Although Mousavi never really spelled out his
much-celebrated economic reform agenda, the very little that he sparingly and
vaguely revealed during the campaign season shows that it was essentially a
capital-friendly reform scheme fashioned after the laissez-faire model of
economics -- often sugar-coated in obfuscationist market terminology such as
market efficiency, entrepreneurial ingenuity, meritocracy, and the like. (This
economic philosophy is interchangeably or synonymously called neoliberal,
neoclassical, trickledown, or supply-side economics; it is also called
economic, or classical, liberalism.)
I imagine the reason Mr. Mousavi never clearly explained his
economic agenda was that he suspected that his ideas of economic liberalism
would not have been very popular with the overwhelming majority of the Iranian
people. Iranians had earlier experienced policies of economic liberalism under
President Rafsanjani (1980-88), which was called �structural adjustment
program.� Judging by people�s reactions to those policies, it is obvious that
they did not care much for them.
It is no longer a secret that Hashemi Rafsanjani was the
main pillar of Mousavi�s presidential campaign. �Since he was defeated by Ahmadinejad in the
presidential elections of 2004,� points out Rostam Pourzal, �Rafsanjani has led
a public crusade against the winner�s zeal for social spending, which he
characterizes as Gadaparvari, or dependency promotion.� Using original
(Farsi) documents, Pourzal further explains how Rafsanjani has for years been
trying to modify Iran�s Constitution in order to facilitate the drive to
deregulation and privatization: �The powerful state Expediency Council, which
Rafsanjani heads, led a reinterpretation of Article 44 of Iran�s constitution
that last June mandated a downsizing of the government in favor of private
investors and contractors. The sale of state-owned industries is advancing
faster than ever, and the introduction of private banking was followed late
last year by the opening of the first foreign bank branch. . . . Yet Rafsanjani�s
powerful allies complain bitterly in public that Ahmadinejad loyalists in the
bureaucracy impede progress towards the competitive economy envisioned in the
new law. This year Mousavi adopted Rafsanjani�s 2004 campaign pledge to
institute �an economic revolution� in which improved efficiency would result
from deregulation.� [10]
Mr. Mousavi expressed his economic agenda in short, cryptic
and patchy statements that were scattered throughout his stump speeches and
other campaign announcements. I sifted through almost all of those speeches and
the one place, perhaps the only place, where I found all of his economic ideas
together in one text was an article that appeared in the 25 May 2009 (4 Khordad 1388, Iranian
calendar) edition of Jomhouri Eslami
newspaper, titled �Mir Hossein Mousavi�s Program for the Improvement of the
National Economy.� Briefly, the following are the main points of his economic
reform agenda, as I have summarized and translated them from Farsi into English
(I am confident my summary reflects his economic reform ideas accurately).
The first and �the key principle for the solution of Iran�s economic
difficulties,� according to Mr. Mousavi�s agenda, was �reform and redefinition
of the executive branch of the government.� This would include reducing the
size of the public sector, curtailing social spending, and bringing
transparency and discipline to financial policies of the government.
The second major principle in his economic program focused
on ways to open more space for business activities of the private sector, and
�to promote the role of this sector in the decision making process of national
economic policies.� Among other issues, this principle included adoption of
policy measures that would expedite the process of market deregulation and revise
constitutional �obstacles� to privatization of public enterprises. Combined
with policy measures to curtail the public sector and the economic role of the
government, these essential steps toward economic liberalization would be
instrumental to the objective of �attracting foreign capital,� his program
maintained.
Within these general principles, Mr. Mousavi occasionally (and, again,
very vaguely) spoke of reducing poverty and unemployment and increasing
homeownership, without explaining how he would achieve these objectives.
Judging by his overall philosophy of economic reform, it is obvious, however,
that he would rely on market efficiency, managerial knowhow, and individual or
entrepreneurial ingenuity to achieve these goals. At one point in his �Program
for the Improvement of the National Economy� he writes, �Today most economists
believe that, within certain ethical framework, individuals� pursuit of
self-enrichment can lead to the collective well-being at the national level.�
This is, of course, the prima-facie beautiful but actually
misleading motto of laissez-faire economic doctrine, and the major justifier of
the unregulated, trickle-down economic philosophy. It is ironic at a time when
this deceptive economic doctrine, which promotes greed as a virtue, is wreaking
havoc in the core capitalist world Mr. Mousavi is trying to promote it in Iran.
A recurring theme in Mr. Mousavi�s economic agenda was bringing down
the oppressively high rates of inflation in Iran, which he blamed on
Ahmadinejad�s government. Why? Because, he argued, Ahmadinejad�s
�out-of-control� social spending and/or subsidies to the poor and working
classes gave them a strong purchasing power that, in turn, led to a strong
demand and, therefore, high inflation. And what was his solution to bring
inflation down? Simple: reduce the size of the public sector, cut social
spending, and promote free enterprise and economic liberalism.
Both Mr. Mousavi�s diagnosis of inflation (social spending) and his
prescription for fighting it (cutting that spending) are based on major
theories of neoliberal economics, which are religiously promoted by the IMF
(International Monetary Fund) and WTO (World Trade Organization) throughout the
world.
While Mr. Mousavi was sparing and ambiguous in terms of a positive
policy agenda for change, he was quite openhanded and expansive on negative
campaigning. In an unfair and obfuscationist manner, he blamed almost all of Iran�s economic
difficulties on Ahmadinejad, thereby overlooking the debilitating effects of
economic and military pressures from abroad.
imusavi�s elections to unseat A--------------- of attracting oitalmentnd activities of the
public sector, these steps toward economic liberalism ry/financial A great deal of Iran�s economic
problems such as inflation and unemployment are due to the suffocating
imperialist economic sanctions and military threats. Since the 1979 revolution,
Iran
has been essentially under both an economic and military siege, ruthlessly
inflicted by US
imperialism and its allies. These destabilizing policies of economic
strangulation have led to capital flight (both human and financial), hoarding
and black-market activities by unscrupulous domestic capitalists, known as
�economic mafias,� and speculative investment in trade and real estate, instead
of long-term investment in productive activities.
A product of the revolution and prime minister for eight years, Mr.
Mousavi must be aware of these debilitating consequences of foreign
interferences on the Iranian economy. Alas, he seems to be more interested in
scoring political points against Ahmadinejad than abiding by the principles of
fairness in judgment.
But then he also blamed Ahmadinejad and his �rash� foreign policy for
the imposition of economic sanctions and military threats from abroad.
Ahmadinejad�s foreign policy has consisted of an uncompromising stance
against the United States and its allies on the issue of Iran�s legitimate
right to nuclear energy, outspoken opposition to the colonial settler state of
Israel, steadfast support for liberation movements in Palestine and Lebanon,
and expanding friendly relations with revolutionary and progressive governments
around the globe, including those of Cuba, Venezuela and Bolivia.
Mousavi and his campaign managers labeled Ahmadinejad�s
foreign policy as �adventurous� and �confrontational,� blaming it for Iran�s
economic difficulties. Accordingly, they sought �understanding� and
�accommodation� with the United States and its allies, presumably including Israel,
in order to achieve political and economic stability. While, prima facie, this
sounds as a reasonable argument (in terms of neoliberal economic solutions to
Iran�s economic problems), it suffers from a number of shortcoming.
To begin with, it is a disingenuous and obfuscationist
argument. Military threats and economic sanctions against Iran did not start
with Ahmadinejad�s presidency, as argued or implied by Mr. Mousavi�s campaign.
They were imposed on Iran nearly thirty years ago, essentially as punishment
for its 1979 revolution that ended the imperialistic US influence over its
economic, political and military affairs.
Second, it is na�ve to think that US imperialism would be
swayed by gentle or polite language to lift economic sanctions or remove military
threats against Iran. During his two terms in office (8 years), the former
president of Iran Muhammad Khatami frequently spoke of �dialogue of
civilizations,� counterposing it to the US Neoconservatives� �clash of
civilization,� effectively begging US imperialism for dialogue and diplomatic
raproachement between Iran and the United States. His pleas of dialogue and
friendship, however, fell on deaf ears. Why?
Because US policy toward Iran (or any other country, for
that matter) is based on an imperialistic agenda that consists of a series of
demands and expectations, not on diplomatic decorum, or the type of language
its leaders use. These include Iran�s giving up its lawful and legitimate right
to civilian nuclear technology, as well as its compliance with the US-Israeli
geopolitical designs in the Middle East. It is not unreasonable to argue that
once Iran allowed US input, or meddling, into such issue of national
sovereignty, it would find itself on a slippery slope the bottom of which would
be giving up its independence: the US would not be satisfied until Iran becomes
another �ally� in the Middle East, more or less like Jordan, Egypt, Saudi
Arabia, and the like.
This is not theoretical; nor is it based on a dark or
cynical suspicion. It is based on the historical record and the nature of US
imperialism, which sees other countries or nations either as its allies or its
enemies. It simply cannot see them as neutral, independent or sovereign
countries. President George W. Bush bluntly expressed this attitude as �you are
either with us or against us.� While other presidents may not put it so
crudely, the policy continues to be a long standing hallmark of imperialistic
US foreign policy.
It is ironic that Mr. Mousavi�s reformist camp blames
Ahmadinejad for the hostile imperialist policies toward Iran. For, US
imperialism showed its most venomous hostility toward Iran during the presidency of Muhammad Khatami (1997-2005), while
he was vigorously pursuing a path of friendship with the United States. While
Khatami was promoting his �dialogue of civilizations� and taking conciliatory
steps to befriend the US, including cooperation in the overthrow of the Taliban
regime in the neighboring Afghanistan, George W. Bush labeled Iran as a member
of the �axis of evil.� This outrageous demonization was then used as a
propaganda tool to justify calls for �regime change� in Iran.
In the face of President Khatami�s conciliatory gestures
toward the United States, many Iranians were so outraged by its unfair and
provocative attitude toward Iran that they began to question the wisdom of
Khatami�s policy of trying to appease US imperialism. It is now widely believed
that the frustration of many Iranians with Khatami�s (one-sided) policy of
dialogue with the United States played a major role in the defeat of his
reformist allies in both the 2003 parliamentary elections and the 2005
presidential election. By the same token, it also played a major role in the
rise of Ahmadinejad to Iran�s presidency, as he forcefully criticized the
reformists� attitude toward US imperialism as na�ve, arguing that negotiation
with the United States must be based on mutual respect, not at the expense of
Iran�s sovereignty.
Contrary to the claims of Mr. Mousavi and his �reformist�
allies, Ahmadinejad is not against (unconditional) negotiation with the US. In
fact, his administration has had (for the past several years) an open
invitation for dialogue with the US. What he is against is submitting to
imperialistic demands and conditions on a number of critical issues that would
go to the heart of Iran�s sovereignty.
Mr. Mousavi�s blaming of Iran�s economic difficulties on
President Ahmadinjad (instead of imperialism�s relentless economic and military
pressures for the past 30 years) is tanatamount to blaming the victim for the
crimes of the perpetrator. Not only is this unfair, it also plays directly into
the hands of Imperialism. Indeed, this is exactly what US imperialism and its
allies have been pursuing (and hoping for) sicnce the 1979 revolution: to exert
so much economic and military pressure on Iran that it eventually breaks down,
and �cries uncle,� so to speak.
This is, by the way, what US imperialism did to the
Sandinista government in Nicaragua in the 1980s. On the one hand, it supported
the opposition to the Sandinistas, including support for the Nicaraguan
terrorist organization called Contras; on the other, it strangled Nicaragua
economically. The combined policies of destabilizing continued unabated until
the US eventually succeeded to bring to power in Nicaragua a regime of its own
liking. [11]
In its zeal to destroy Ahmadinejad�s record, Mr. Mousavi�s campaign did
not hesitate to also distort, tarnish, or downplay Iran�s progress since the 1979
revolution. Despite all the shortcomings, the fact remains that the revolution
ushered in significant progress in many social and economic areas of the
Iranian society. These include extension of transportation, communication and
electrification networks to the countryside; provision of free education and
healthcare services for the needy; reduction of poverty and inequality; and
more.
Iran has also made considerable progress in scientific research and
technological know-how. All the oppressive economic sanctions by US imperialism
and its allies have not deterred Iran from forging ahead with its
economic development and industrialization plans. Indeed, Iran has viewed
imperialism�s economic sanctions and technological boycotts as a blessing in
disguise: it has taken advantage of these sanctions and boycotts to become
self-reliant in many technological areas.
For example, Iran is now self-sufficient in producing many of its
industrial products such as home and electric appliances (television sets,
washers and dryers, refrigerators, washing machines, and the like), textiles,
leather products, pharmaceuticals, and agricultural products and processed food
and beverage products (including refined sugar and vegetable oil). The country
has also made considerable progress in manufacturing steel, copper products,
paper, rubber products, telecommunications equipment, cement, and industrial
machinery. �Iran
has the largest operational stock of industrial robots in West Asia.� [12]
Iran�s progress in automobile and other motor vehicle production has
especially been impressive. Motor vehicles, including farming equipment, now
count among Iran�s
exports. �As of 2001, there were 13 public and privately owned
automakers within Iran. . . . These automakers produce a wide range of automobiles
including motorbikes, passenger cars, vans, mini trucks, medium sized trucks,
heavy duty trucks, minibuses, large size buses and other heavy automobiles used
in commercial and private activities in the country. Iran ranked the world�s
16th biggest automaker in 2006.� [13]
Most remarkable of Iran�s
industrial progress, however, can be seen in the manufacture of various types
of its armaments needs. �Iran�s defense industry has taken great strides in the
past 25 years, and now manufactures many types of arms and equipment. Since
1992, Iran�s Defense Industries Organization (DIO) has produced its own tanks,
armored personnel carriers, guided missiles, radar systems, military vessels,
submarines, and a fighter plane. . . . As of 2006, Iran had
exported weapons to 57 countries, including NATO members.� Compared with other
countries, Iran�s
military budget is surprisingly modest. �Iran�s 2005 defense budget was
estimated to be $6.2 billion (3.3% of GDP) [less than 1% of US military
spending] . . . ranking the 67th largest defense expenditure globally.� [14]
Perhaps most important of Iran�s achievements since the 1979
revolution, however, has been its independence from the influence of foreign
powers -- something that many people in other countries in the region (and
beyond) are envious of. Iran
is perhaps the only country in the area that determines its own economic,
political and military policies independently of foreign powers� advisors,
guidelines and dictates. (This is, by the way, the main reason for US
imperialism�s hostility toward Iran.
All other alleged reasons such as �weaponization of its nuclear technology,
support for terrorism, existential threat to Israel, denial of Holocaust,� and
the like are no more than harebrained excuses for its evil plans of �regime
change� in Iran.)
Just as Mr. Mousavi was vague and cryptic about his agenda of economic
reform, so was he fuzzy on the issues of democracy and human rights. He spoke
of individual liberty and human rights in such abstract and general terms as if
human rights had nothing to do with the right to basic human needs such as food
and shelter, or the right to affordable healthcare and public education. In
this respect, too, Mr. Mousavi�s agenda resembled those of the leaders of other
color revolutions -- for example, of Mikheil Saakashvili in Georgia and of
Viktor Yushchenko in Ukraine.
Had he succeeded in carrying out his �green revolution,� his promises of
democracy and human rights would have proven as hollow as those of his
counterparts in Georgia and Ukraine.
The empty promises of democracy and human rights by leaders of color
revolutions stems not so much from their personal traits as they do from the
reform agendas they pursue. At the heart of those reform agendas is an economic
restructuring program that is based on deregulation, curtailment of social
spending and privatization of public enterprises. As such capital-friendly
measures threaten the economic safety-net programs of the poor and working
classes, they will resist, and sometimes rebel. And that�s where the promised
democracy of the �reform� leaders of color revolutions will end; they will not
hesitate to call on their �security� forces to quell the grassroots� resistance
to the curtailment of their basic needs.
This is, of course, not limited to the leaders of color revolution; it
is in the nature of the so-called bourgeois (capitalist) democracy to bury the
more critical economic rights of the poor and working classes beneath the
superficial, purely political individual rights, such as, for example,
periodically voting to change the faces of politicians who hold public office
without really changing their policy agendas in meaningful ways.
To suggest that Mousavi�s projected �green revolution� bore
all the major hallmarks of the previous color-coded revolutions, or that the
subversive US agencies and policies for �regime change� supported and/or
promoted his campaign, is not to suggest or imply that he (personally)
collaborated with those agencies. Mr. Mousavi is no pawn of imperialism. But
the logic of things, the mechanism of his campaign, or the internal dynamics of
his agenda, inevitably led to an unmistakable convergence between the interests
of imperialism, headed by the US, and those of Mousavi�s campaign architects
over the removal of Ahmadinejad from power. Not surprisingly, the two campaigns
to overthrow Ahmadinejad complemented each other conveniently.
Whether this was purely coincidental or by design is hard to
judge, unless one has irrefutable proof. Nor is the proof of such a link, or
lack thereof, the primary focus of this essay. Rather, the more important point
here is that by prematurely claiming election victory, and then recklessly
insisting that the contrary voting results meant �stolen election,� Mr. Mousavi
was less than honest with his supporters, and the Iranian people in general.
Whether he consciously agreed to this scheme of his campaign architects, or was
really duped by those architects to sincerely (or delusively) believe he had
won the elections, is of secondary importance. The more important point is that
by so doing he effectively became the leader and the face of an electoral coup
attempt -- whether he was mindful of it or not, or whether he liked it or not.
The claim of �people�s votes being stolen� is so loaded and
so powerful that not only would the supporters of the opposition promptly rebel
against the incumbent, but also many other citizens who may not have been
supporters or sympathizers of the opposition but are angered by the thought of
their votes being �stolen.� While this scheme of power gabbing succeeded in
Georgia, Ukraine and a number of other so-called �emerging democracies,� it
failed in Venezuela and Iran.
Part of the reason for the failure of Mr. Mousavi�s �green
revolution� was that his unscrupulous negative campaigning backfired -- Ahmadinejad
did not let him get away with it. To be sure, Mr. Mousavi did get away many
falsehoods and distortions in his stump speeches during the campaign season.
But when Ahmadinejad confronted him during the famous presidential debate of
the week before the election date, Mousavi came up short. He did not offer much
in the way of a positive agenda to his audience of more than 45 million
Iranians who reportedly watched the debate. As Ahmadinejad successfully pinned
him down to the notorious Rafsanjani and other rich and corrupt backers of his
campaign, he basically sat there speechless. Although his campaign was
increasingly catching up with that of Ahmadinejad during the previous three
weeks, the debate effectively turned the tide.
During the debate, Ahmadinejad attacked Mousavi�s affluent
backers as leaders of the corrupt elite, now trying to claw back control. He
threatened to curtail the waste and inefficiency of many of the redundant
monopolistic organizations, as well as re-take the �embezzled� people�s
property from the oligarchs. He also bitterly complained about the resistance
(by the representatives of the wealthy) to his idea of a progressive taxation
system that would reduce Iran�s
dependence on oil revenue. Most impressive and effective in terms of winning
voters away from Mousavi, however, was his leafing through written documents
that he said were evidence of scandalous privatizations, unscrupulous
appropriation of public property, and predatory land grabbing by the pillars of
Mousavi�s campaign during the presidencies of Khatami and Rafsanjani.
5. The demonstrators
The suggestion that the Mousavi campaign seems to have
planned a �green revolution� in the context of the presidential election, or
that the projected revolution was enthusiastically supported by the forces of
�regime change� from abroad, is not meant to discount the significance of the
large number of sincere protesters who took to the street following the claim
that their votes were �stolen.� In light of their huge numbers and their
diversity, the protesters cannot be dismissed as simply or only the better-off
and the better-educated. But while young protestors from different walks of the
Iranian society joined the rallies, the leadership and the management of
demonstrations rested largely with the powerful behind-the-scene interests and
shadowy agitators. [15]
Although the two relatively different types of protesters,
the elite and the common folks, shared some grievances regarding social and/or
cultural restrictions such as moral or dress codes, their economic needs and
aspirations were vastly different. To the extent that young people form lower
income strata participated in the protest rallies, they did so because they
hoped for better employment opportunities and decent social safety-net programs
such as support for public education, public health and other basic economic
needs. These folks were largely unaware that a Mousavi victory would have, in
fact, meant curtailing, not advancing, such economic safety-net programs.
By contrast, the oligarchs and their elite allies, that is,
the leading or managing protestors, participated in protest rallies because
they aspired to the consumerism and the life style of their counterparts in the
West. They were also seeking free trade and investment opportunities with
Western markets and transnational corporations. As Phil Wilayto, author of In
Defense of Iran, points out, �They [the wealthy] aren�t just opposing the
government of President Mahmoud Ahmadinejad -- they�re also objectively
opposing millions of working-class Iranians who are trying to defend the social
programs that have greatly improved their standard of living, programs that
depend on the state ownership of the oil and gas industries.� [16]
Contrary to protesters from among the ordinary citizens, the
affluent demonstrators had no illusions about Mousavi�s �reform� agenda. They
had, indeed, crafted that agenda. A telling indication of this point is the
fact Rafsanjani (and his wealthy allies) constituted the backbone, the leading
force, and financial benefactors of the Mousavi campaign. In 2005, the German newspaper
taz provided a blunt profile of Rafsanjani and his family: �The man of
God, who once earned a meager living preaching heavenly redemption for
believers, now possesses a fortune estimated at more than a billion US dollars.
He is Iran�s
largest exporter of pistachios. Together with his family, he owns several
tourist centers both at home and abroad. His oldest son Mohsen is constructing
the Tehran
underground; his second son Mehdi is in the natural gas and oil business; his
youngest son owns vast swathes of agricultural land; his two daughters Faezeh
and Fatima are active in real estate both in Iran and abroad. Rafsanjani�s
cousins, nephews and nieces own a considerable portion of the domestic
automobile industry, as well as controlling much of the export of pistachios
and saffron, and the import of vehicles, paper and machines. A considerable
part of Iran�s black market is controlled by the Rafsanjani clan. [17]
It is well known among Iranians that Rafsanjani and other
influential backers of Mousavi are not motivated by concerns for the democratic
and human rights of the Iranian people. Nor are they motivated by concerns for
the plight of their economic conditions. �On the contrary,� points out Bill Van
Auken, a freelance reporter and an astute observer of Iranian politics, �they
are proponents of a more rapid introduction of free market policies, an opening
to foreign capital and closer ties with Washington, all of which they see as
avenues for expanding their own wealth. Their indifference to the conditions
confronting the broad masses of Iranian working people is expressed in their
undisguised contempt for the limited social assistance programs introduced by
Ahmadinejad, which they see as a waste of resources.� [18]
Not only were many of the young protesters misled by the
demagogic promises of the Mousavi campaign, they were also misled by the flood
of propaganda that is constantly fed the Iranian people from abroad via
internet and satellite media. Farsi-language radio and television propaganda
broadcasts from the Los Angeles
area by the opposition expatriates are especially deceptive to the Iranian
youth. One of the challenges I recently faced during my visit to Iran (as well
as during previous visits) was to reason with the young Iranians I spoke with
to not believe everything they hear or see on these broadcast systems from
abroad. They could not believe that, for example, there is unemployment,
poverty and homelessness in the United
States. The picture portrayed (by the
opposition propaganda from abroad) of the living conditions in the US remains
essentially the same as conveyed around the world via the glamorous Hollywood movies of long ago.
Mr. Mousavi and his supporters claim that post-election
demonstrations in favor of his �green revolution� were altogether peaceful.
Accordingly, they blame the government for the post-election violence and the
crackdown on demonstrators. Reports by major Western media from Iran show,
however, that it was, in fact, the protesters who started the violence. For
example, on 13 June 2009 (the day after the Election Day) The New York Times reported from Tehran: �Farther down the street,
clusters of young men hurled rocks at a phalanx of riot police officers, and
the police used their batons to beat back protesters. . . . As night settled
in, the streets in northern Tehran that recently had been the scene of
pre-election euphoria were lit by the flames of trash fires and blocked by
tipped trash bins and at least one charred bus. Young men ran through the
streets throwing paving stones at shop windows, and the police pursued them.�
On the same day (June 13) the Associated Press similarly reported: �Opponents of Mahmoud
Ahmadinejad clashed with police in the heart of Iran�s capital Saturday,
pelting them with rocks and setting fires in the worst unrest in Tehran in a
decade. . . . The brazen and angry confrontations -- including stunning scenes
of masked rioters tangling with black-clad police -- pushed the self-styled
reformist movement closer to a possible moment of truth. . . . Young men hurled
stones and bottles at anti-riot units and mocked Ahmadinejad as an illegitimate
leader. . . . Thousands of protesters -- mostly young men -- roamed through
Tehran looking for a fight with police and setting trash bins and tires ablaze.
Pillars of black smoke rose among the mustard-colored apartment blocks and
office buildings in central Tehran. In one side road, an empty bus was engulfed
in flames. Police fought back with clubs, including mobile squads on motorcycles
swinging truncheons.
�Thousands of protesters -- mostly young men -- roamed
through Tehran looking for a fight with police. . . .� Does this sound peaceful
to anyone?
And here is a CNN report, also on June 13, from Tehran: �In
the aftermath of the vote, street protesters and riot police engaged in running
battles, with stones thrown, garbage cans set on fire and people shouting �death
to the dictatorship.� . . . Later in the evening, an agitated and angry crowd
emerged in Tehran�s Moseni Square, with people breaking into shops, starting
fires and tearing down signs.�
Two days later, June 15, Time
Magazine had a similar report from Tehran: �Some of Tehran�s main streets
have been turned into urban battlegrounds. Groups of mostly young men have set
large garbage bins on fire in the middle of streets, torn out street signs and
fences, broken the windows and ATM machines of state banks and burnt at least
five large buses in the middle of streets.�
The June 15, 2009 clashes between demonstrators and the security
forces around the Azadi square further escalated, claiming seven lives, the
first election-related deaths. Reporting on the tragic confrontation, the Associated Press wrote: �Iran state
radio reported Tuesday [June 16] that clashes in the Iranian capital the
previous day left seven people dead during an �unauthorized gathering� at a
mass rally over alleged election fraud -- the first official confirmation of
deaths linked to the wave of protests and street battles after the elections.
The report said the deaths occurred after protesters �tried to attack a
military location.� It gave no further details, but it was a clear reference to
crowds who came under gunfire Monday after trying to storm a compound for
volunteer militia linked to Iran�s powerful Revolutionary Guard. . . . The
deaths Monday occurred on the edge of Tehran�s Azadi Square. An Associated
Press photographer saw gunmen, standing on a roof, opening fire on a group of
demonstrators who tried to storm the militia compound.�
Commenting on this dreadful shooting of the protestors by
the members of the Basij militia, Phil Wilayto, author of In Defense of Iran, writes: �It�s terrible that seven people died.
But the Basij members were in a building set on fire by �protesters,� who were
trying to storm the building. What were they supposed to do?� [19]
These reports by some of the most established news media in
the West makes it clear that, by resorting to illegal and vilolent methods of
demonstration, the protestors did not leave government�s security forces much
choice to react violently. No other government would tolerate such methods of
protest. Imagine for a moment that on the day after last November�s
presidential election in the United States John McCain�s supporters, following
his encouragement, challenged the elections results, took to the streets and
began destroying public property, or attacking police stations. It goes without
saying that the response of the US security forces would have been more violent
and much swifter than that of Iran�s. US security forces would certainly have
not waited for three or four days (as did Iran�s) to react; their reaction
would have been immediate.
It must be pointed out that reports of violent demonstrators
by the mainstream Western media came to a sudden halt after June 19, 2009. Why?
Because on that day the US Congress, both the House and the Senate, passed
resolutions that condemned the Iranian security forces� crackdown on demonstrators
as unprovoked, thereby effectively characterizing the protests as peaceful.
Shamelessly, the corporate media followed the official line
through-and-through.
6. Concluding remarks
One does not have to be a fan of Ahmadinejad to find his opponents�
�green revolution� a dubious -- perhaps disgraceful -- project. Mr. Mousavi
and/or his campaign architects seem to have run a dishonest campaign:
pretending to rely on the ballot box to carry out their �reform� agenda but,
then, disobeying the will of the majority when they did not garner the majority
vote. As noted earlier, it is one thing to use the voters� dissatisfaction with
the status quo to win an election. It is quite another thing, however, to abuse
that dissatisfaction and the election process to defy the actual election
results when those results turn out to be at variance with what you wishfully
projected.
In the absence of irrefutable evidence, it would be unwise
to make a judgment on whether Mr. Mousavi personally conspired with his
campaign architects on the �green revolution� project, or whether he was led to
sincerely believe he could not have lost the election. Likewise, short of
concrete evidence, it would be imprudent to make a judgment on whether his
campaign consciously collaborated with the external forces of �regime change�
in Iran.
Nor is the proof (or disproof) of such links germane to the primary intention
of this essay. The primary purpose of the essay has, instead, been to show
that, regardless of external factors or Mr. Mousavi�s personal proclivities,
powerful economic interests, or influential social forces, behind his �green
revolution� evolved within Iran�s
own socio-economic structure.
As it is increasingly becoming clear that the claim of
�stolen election� was a hoax, Mr. Mousavi and his supporters seem to be quietly
shying away from repeating that gigantic lie. Instead, they tend to play up the
large number of protesters who supported his campaign and the subsequently
heavy-handed crackdown on demonstrators as if these would prove that he did not
or could not have lost the election. As a way of (quietly) departing from the
claim of �stolen election,� as if changing the subject, some of his supporters
make arguments like this: �Don�t you see the huge, frustrated and angry number
of demonstrators? Doesn�t this show how tired people are of this dictatorial
regime? Who cares about the official account of the elections; they are
inherently undemocratic in the theocratic Islamic Republic anyway? Don�t you
see how thirsty people are for change? Isn�t this proof enough to get rid of
Ahmadinejad�s regime? And so on.� Let us briefly examine these arguments.
To begin with, as great as the number of opposition
demonstrators were they remained nonetheless a minority of the electorate.
Pro-Ahmadinejad counter demonstrations, allowed only a few times, literally
dwarfed those who demonstrated in support of Mousavi. (Critics of �color
revolutions� point out that one of the strategies of the leaders of these
revolutions to create chaos, confusion and instability has been to resort to
violence and provoke counter demonstrations. Ahmadinejad�s government seems to
have avoided this trap by actively discouraging pro-government counter
demonstrations.)
Secondly, and perhaps more importantly, the problem with Mr.
Mousavi�s campaign was not his giving voice to people�s grievances, or trying
to affect an agenda of positive change in Iran. Rather, it was his method or
strategy of change that was problematic. As if the end justifies the means, his
campaign seemed to have followed a less-than honest strategy to achieve its
goal of removing Ahmadinejad from power. Mr. Mousavi accepted Iran�s legal
and institutional norms when he decided to run as a candidate for president.
Indeed, he greatly benefitted from those legal and institutional procedures in
running a very effective campaign. Somewhere along the way his campaign decided
to disobey those guideline when they became convinced their candidate would
lose (or had actually lost) the election. In trying to use the impressive
energy of the remarkably galvanized supporters of Mr. Mousavi as a lever to
illegally dislodge President Ahmadinejad, his campaign effectively betrayed the
trust his supporters had placed in his candidacy.
Not only has the insidious project of �green revolution�
paved the way for a lot of unnecessary death and destruction, it has also
provided the imperial forces of �regime change� with additional excuses to
re-double their brutal efforts of economic sanctions and military threats
against Iran, thereby further aggravating the economic hardship and the living
conditions of the Iranian people. Mr. Mousavi and his campaign architects
simply cannot dodge responsibility for the dire consequences of their �green
revolution.�
References
[1] Please see, for example, Habib Ahmadzadeh: �Mousavi Must Say Which Ballot Boxes He
Disputes,� Daily Kos (June 29, 2009); Phil Wilayto,
�An Open Letter to the Anti-War Movement,� CASMII
(July 9, 2009); �A Review of the
Chatham House report on Iran�s 2009 presidential election,� CASMII (August 4, 2009).
[2] Paul Craig
Roberts, �Are the Iranian Election Protests Another
U.S. Orchestrated �Color Revolution�?� Creators.com (June 20, 2009).
[3] Please see, for example, Ken Ballen and Patrick Doherty �The
Iranian People Speak,� The Washington
Post (June 15, 2009);
Flynt Leverett and Hillary Mann Leverett, �Ahmadinejad Won.
Get over it,� Politico (June 15,
2009); Jeremy R. Hammond, �The
Case of the Fatwa to Rig Iran�s Election,� Dissent Voice (July 22, 2009).
[4] Thierry Meyssan, �Color revolution
fails in Iran,� voltairenet.org (June 27, 2009); �The Albert Einstein Institution: non-violence
according to the CIA,� voltairenet.org (4 January 2005).
[5] Philip Giraldi, �Twittering
Revolutions,� Antiwar.com (July 16, 2009).
[6] Stephen Lendman,
�Color Revolutions, Old and New,� GlobalResearch.ca
(July 1, 2009).
[7] Thierry Meyssan, �Color revolution
fails in Iran,� voltairenet.org (June 27, 2009).
[8] Rostam Pourzal, �Iran�s Business
Elite, Too, Is a �Dissident�,� MRZine
(27 June 2009).
[9] Reuters, �Ahmadinejad
to focus subsidies on Iran�s poor� (June 25, 2008).
[10] Rostam Pourzal, �Iran�s Business
Elite, Too, Is a �Dissident�,� MRZine (June 27, 2009).
[11] Eric Walberg, �Venezuela & Iran: Whither the Revolution?� GlobalResearch.ca
(1 July 2009).
[12] Wikipedia, �Economy of Iran --
Manufacturing�
[13] Ibid.
[14] Ibid.
[15] Mazda Majidi, �Eyewitness Iran:
What is the true character of the demonstrations,� CASMII (7 July 2009).
[16] Phil Wilayto, �An Open Letter to the Anti-War Movement,� CASMII
(July 9, 2009).
[17] Bill Van Auken, �Tensions mount
within Iran�s ruling establishment,� World
Socialist Web Site (21
July 2009).
[18] Ibid.
[19] Phil Wilayto, �An Open Letter to the Anti-War Movement� CASMII
(July 9, 2009).
Ismael Hossein-zadeh,
author of the recently published The
Political Economy of U.S. Militarism
(Palgrave-Macmillan 2007), teaches economics at Drake University, Des Moines,
Iowa.