Last week, the Commerce Department reported the 2007 current
account deficit was $738.6 billion, down from $811.5 billion in 2006. The
deficit exceeded 5.3 percent of GDP. The fourth quarter deficit was $172.9
billion.
The current account is the broadest measure of the U.S.
trade balance. In addition to trade in goods and services, it includes income
received from U.S. investments abroad less payments to foreigners on their
investments in the United States.
In the 2007, the United States had a $106.9 surplus on trade
in services and a $106.9 billion surplus on income payments. This was hardly
enough to offset the massive $815.9 billion deficit on trade in goods, and net
unilateral transfers to foreigners equal to $104.4 billion.
The huge deficit on trade in goods is mostly caused by a
combination of an overvalued dollar against the Chinese yuan, a dysfunctional
national energy policy that increases U.S. dependence on foreign oil, and the
competitive woes of the three domestic automakers. Together, the trade deficit
with China and on petroleum and automotive products total at least 100 percent
of the deficit on trade in goods and services.
To finance the current account deficit, Americans are
borrowing and selling assets at a pace of $600 billion a year. U.S. foreign
debt is about $6.5 trillion. At 5 percent interest, the debt service would come
to about $2000 a year for every working American.
The current account deficit imposes a significant tax on GDP
growth by moving workers from export and import-competing industries to other
sectors of the economy. This reduces labor productivity, research and
development spending, and important investments in human capital. In 2007 the
trade deficit is slicing about $250 billion off GDP, and longer term, it
reduces potential annual GDP growth to about 3 percent from about 4 percent.
Financing the deficit
The current account deficit must be financed by a capital account
surplus, either by foreigners investing in the U.S. economy or loaning
Americans money. Some analysts argue that the deficit reflects U.S. economic
strength, because foreigners find many promising investments here. The details
of U.S. financing belie this argument.
U.S. investments abroad were $1,206.3 billion, while
foreigners invested $1,863.7 billion in the United States. Of that latter
total, only $204 billion or 11 percent was direct investment in U.S. productive
assets. The remaining net capital inflows were foreign purchases of Treasury
securities, corporate bonds, bank accounts, currency, and other paper assets.
Essentially, Americans borrowed or sold off real estate and other assets of
about $600 billion to consume about 5.3 percent more than they produced.
Foreign governments loaned Americans $412.7 billion or 3
percent of GDP. The Chinese and other governments are essentially bankrolling
U.S. consumers, who in turn are mortgaging their children�s income.
The cumulative effects of this borrowing are frightening.
The total external debt now is about $6.5 trillion. The debt service at 5
percent interest, amounts to $2000 for each working American.
The Chinese government alone holds enough U.S. and other
foreign reserves to purchase about 10 percent of the shares of all publicly
traded U.S. companies. The U.S. trade deficit is the primary driver behind this
phenomenon.
Consequences for economic growth
High and rising trade deficits tax economic growth.
Specifically, each dollar spent on imports that is not matched by a dollar of
exports reduces domestic demand and employment, and shifts workers into
activities where productivity is lower.
Productivity is at least 50 percent higher in industries
that export and compete with imports, and reducing the trade deficit and moving
workers into these industries would increase GDP.
Were the trade deficit cut in half, GDP would increase by
about $250 billion or more than $1,700 for every working American. Workers�
wages would not be lagging inflation, and ordinary working Americans would more
easily find jobs paying higher wages and offering decent benefits.
Manufacturers are particularly hard hit by this subsidized
competition. Through recession and recovery, the manufacturing sector has lost
3.6 million jobs since 2000. Following the pattern of past economic recoveries,
the manufacturing sector should have regained at least 2 million of those jobs,
especially given the very strong productivity growth accomplished in durable
goods and throughout manufacturing.
Longer-term, persistent U.S. trade deficits are a
substantial drag on growth. U.S. import-competing and export industries spend
three times the national average on industrial R&D, and encourage more
investments in skills and education than other sectors of the economy. By
shifting employment away from trade-competing industries, the trade deficit
reduces U.S. investments in new methods and products, and skilled labor.
Cutting the trade deficit in half would boost U.S. GDP
growth by one percentage point a year, and the trade deficits of the last two
decades have reduced U.S. growth by one percentage point a year.
Lost growth is cumulative. Thanks to the record trade
deficits accumulated over the last 10 years, the U.S. economy is about $1.5
trillion smaller. This comes to about $10,000 per worker.
Had the administration and the Congress acted responsibly to
reduce the deficit, American workers would be much better off, tax revenues
would be much larger, and the federal deficit could be eliminated without
cutting spending.
The damage grows larger each month, as the Bush
administration dallies and ignores the corrosive consequences of the trade
deficit.
Peter
Morici is a professor at the University of Maryland School of Business and
former Chief Economist at the U.S. International Trade Commission.